Asean
India’s seasons of inflation?
Author: Mathew Joseph, ICRIER Food inflation is reaching new heights in India, petrol prices have seen a hike for the second time in a month and the crisis is now threatening to arrest the country’s growth momentum. But to put the blame on crop failure alone, as the government is trying to do, is erroneous. Food inflation crossed the 20 per cent mark in December 2009 and remained at that level for several months. Wholesale price inflation moved to double-digits in March 2010. The wholesale price inflation and food inflation did come down from July 2010. After respite for a few months, inflation went up again in December 2010 and indications are that it will remain at uncomfortable levels for some time. The normal monsoon and expectations of a rebound in agricultural output are not providing the usual dampening effect on prices this time. In India, inflation is usually triggered by a poor agricultural crop. And the two successive poor kharif (summer) crops in 2008 and 2009 are considered to be behind the current inflationary situation. But then why has the normal crop of this year failed to subdue the rate of inflation? During the low-inflationary first half of the 2000s, the year 2002–03 stands out. In that year a severe rain shortfall brought down foodgrain production by 18 per cent, leading to a drop in agricultural GDP by 7 per cent. Still, inflation hardly rose in 2002–03 and averaged at about 3–4 per cent, the same as in 2001–02. Why? The seeming anomaly of low inflation in 2002–03 coinciding with a sharp decline in food output is explained by the fact that the previous year had seen a bumper crop which helped replenish public-sector food stocks sufficiently for the government to intervene effectively to keep prices down. The government released adequate grains through the public distribution system as well as open market sales. By contrast, the monsoon failure in 2009–10 followed a subnormal kharif crop in 2008–09; food stocks with the government at the end of 2008–09, and public release of these stocks in 2008–09 and 2009–10, were lower than in 2002–03. Also in 2002–03, the government kept the procurement price the same as in the previous year, except that a special one-time drought relief of Rp20 for a quintal of paddy and Rp10 for a quintal of wheat were added to the existing price. The drought in 2009–10, in contrast, followed a period of continuous and substantial annual increases in procurement prices since 2006–07. It, therefore, added to the upward pressure on food prices. The experience of 2002–03 demolishes the thesis that high inflation is inevitable when there is a crop failure. The fact is that the crop failures in 2008–09 and 2009–10 with no absolute decline in agricultural GDP were much less serious than the drop in 2002–03, when there was a huge decline in output. What mattered was the difference in government procurement, pricing and distribution policies between then and now. The main difference, however, is the demand situation and that mattered more. Since 2002–03, the GDP growth broke all previous records and the economy grew by an average of nearly 9 per cent per annum in the next five years. This implied a rise in per capita income in real terms at nearly 7.5 per cent per annum. During this period the per capita availability of major food crops had been, on the contrary, either stagnating or declining. Thus, while the flare up in inflation from 2008–09 can be attributed to crop failures, the building up of inflationary pressures since 2006 is due to the rising food demand-supply gap during the period. As the global crisis hit the world, all countries followed ultra-loose fiscal and monetary policies in 2008 and 2009. The Indian economy recovered from the second quarter of 2009–10, showing an average year-on-year growth of 7.9 per cent in the last three quarters of 2009–10 against an average growth of 6.1 per cent in the previous three quarters. The growth rate picked up further to 8.9 per cent in the first two quarters of 2010–11. As the economy picked up inflation also rose. Food inflation rose to 17.1 per cent during the last three quarters of 2009–10 from 10.8 per cent in the previous three quarters and further up to 18.8 per cent in the first two quarters of 2010–11. Wholesale Price Index (WPI) inflation rose to 4.7 per cent in the last three quarters of 2009–10 and shot up further to 9.9 per cent in the first two quarters of 2010–11. The Reserve Bank of India (RBI) began its monetary tightening only from mid-February 2010 , initially by raising the cash reserve ratio of banks, and the rate tightening began later from mid-March 2010. Since March, the repo rate has been raised seven times, each time by 25 basis points. The very high food inflation (17.1 per cent) and the CPI(Industrial Workers) inflation (13.5 per cent) during the last three quarters of 2009–10 clearly required the RBI to act earlier . In the short term, the only option available is a harder monetary tightening. It should be difficult to purge out the inflationary expectations that have got entrenched by now. The consequent rise in interest rates is bound to reduce corporate profitability and bring growth down. This is the inevitable cost that has to be incurred for bringing inflation down. Fundamentally, India is confronting a binding food constraint to its growth beyond the 7–8 per cent rate. To avoid a return to the pre-2000 period of inflation, India has to remove all the constraints against a breakthrough in food production. This requires agricultural reforms. The earlier round of reforms carried out in the 1990s were focused on industry, foreign trade, foreign investment and the financial sector, bypassing agriculture. The next round of reforms that is needed for raising India’s potential growth rate beyond 7–8 per cent should essentially have agriculture as an important component. The persistence of high inflation is rooted in the inability to raise food production in step with the rise in demand arising from increasing population and per capita income growth. The present ‘subsidy-control regime’ in agriculture is strangling the farmer and preventing him from achieving a breakthrough in production. The input subsidies provided through low or no price for water, electricity and urea fertilisers not only lead to overuse and erosion of soil fertility, but also ensures inefficient production of these inputs by companies. Farmers can sell their products only through government markets which involve a large number of intermediaries and lower prices. Consumer subsidies administered through the public distribution system lead to low food prices which scarcely reach the consumers as large scale leakages take place. On the other hand, the government’s food procurement with periodical hiking of the procurement prices leads to market shortages and rising food prices. Agricultural reform is the key to controlling inflation. That should involve lifting of government controls on pricing of all inputs and outputs, abolition of the monopsony of government mandis and administering all subsidies through direct cash transfers to poor farmers (owning land below two hectares) and poor consumers (below the poverty line). Mathew Joseph is a Senior Consultant at the Indian Council for Research and International Economic Relations (ICRIER), New Delhi. India: Controlling inflation without hurting growth Indian monetary policy and the RBI – Let’s focus upon inflation India’s need for a counter-inflation subsidy
Author: Mathew Joseph, ICRIER
Food inflation is reaching new heights in India, petrol prices have seen a hike for the second time in a month and the crisis is now threatening to arrest the country’s growth momentum. But to put the blame on crop failure alone, as the government is trying to do, is erroneous.
Food inflation crossed the 20 per cent mark in December 2009 and remained at that level for several months. Wholesale price inflation moved to double-digits in March 2010. The wholesale price inflation and food inflation did come down from July 2010. After respite for a few months, inflation went up again in December 2010 and indications are that it will remain at uncomfortable levels for some time. The normal monsoon and expectations of a rebound in agricultural output are not providing the usual dampening effect on prices this time.
In India, inflation is usually triggered by a poor agricultural crop. And the two successive poor kharif (summer) crops in 2008 and 2009 are considered to be behind the current inflationary situation. But then why has the normal crop of this year failed to subdue the rate of inflation?
During the low-inflationary first half of the 2000s, the year 2002–03 stands out. In that year a severe rain shortfall brought down foodgrain production by 18 per cent, leading to a drop in agricultural GDP by 7 per cent. Still, inflation hardly rose in 2002–03 and averaged at about 3–4 per cent, the same as in 2001–02. Why?
The seeming anomaly of low inflation in 2002–03 coinciding with a sharp decline in food output is explained by the fact that the previous year had seen a bumper crop which helped replenish public-sector food stocks sufficiently for the government to intervene effectively to keep prices down. The government released adequate grains through the public distribution system as well as open market sales. By contrast, the monsoon failure in 2009–10 followed a subnormal kharif crop in 2008–09; food stocks with the government at the end of 2008–09, and public release of these stocks in 2008–09 and 2009–10, were lower than in 2002–03. Also in 2002–03, the government kept the procurement price the same as in the previous year, except that a special one-time drought relief of Rp20 for a quintal of paddy and Rp10 for a quintal of wheat were added to the existing price. The drought in 2009–10, in contrast, followed a period of continuous and substantial annual increases in procurement prices since 2006–07. It, therefore, added to the upward pressure on food prices.
The experience of 2002–03 demolishes the thesis that high inflation is inevitable when there is a crop failure. The fact is that the crop failures in 2008–09 and 2009–10 with no absolute decline in agricultural GDP were much less serious than the drop in 2002–03, when there was a huge decline in output. What mattered was the difference in government procurement, pricing and distribution policies between then and now. The main difference, however, is the demand situation and that mattered more.
Since 2002–03, the GDP growth broke all previous records and the economy grew by an average of nearly 9 per cent per annum in the next five years. This implied a rise in per capita income in real terms at nearly 7.5 per cent per annum. During this period the per capita availability of major food crops had been, on the contrary, either stagnating or declining.
Thus, while the flare up in inflation from 2008–09 can be attributed to crop failures, the building up of inflationary pressures since 2006 is due to the rising food demand-supply gap during the period.
As the global crisis hit the world, all countries followed ultra-loose fiscal and monetary policies in 2008 and 2009. The Indian economy recovered from the second quarter of 2009–10, showing an average year-on-year growth of 7.9 per cent in the last three quarters of 2009–10 against an average growth of 6.1 per cent in the previous three quarters. The growth rate picked up further to 8.9 per cent in the first two quarters of 2010–11. As the economy picked up inflation also rose. Food inflation rose to 17.1 per cent during the last three quarters of 2009–10 from 10.8 per cent in the previous three quarters and further up to 18.8 per cent in the first two quarters of 2010–11. Wholesale Price Index (WPI) inflation rose to 4.7 per cent in the last three quarters of 2009–10 and shot up further to 9.9 per cent in the first two quarters of 2010–11.
The Reserve Bank of India (RBI) began its monetary tightening only from mid-February 2010, initially by raising the cash reserve ratio of banks, and the rate tightening began later from mid-March 2010. Since March, the repo rate has been raised seven times, each time by 25 basis points. The very high food inflation (17.1 per cent) and the CPI(Industrial Workers) inflation (13.5 per cent) during the last three quarters of 2009–10 clearly required the RBI to act earlier.
In the short term, the only option available is a harder monetary tightening. It should be difficult to purge out the inflationary expectations that have got entrenched by now. The consequent rise in interest rates is bound to reduce corporate profitability and bring growth down. This is the inevitable cost that has to be incurred for bringing inflation down.
Fundamentally, India is confronting a binding food constraint to its growth beyond the 7–8 per cent rate. To avoid a return to the pre-2000 period of inflation, India has to remove all the constraints against a breakthrough in food production. This requires agricultural reforms. The earlier round of reforms carried out in the 1990s were focused on industry, foreign trade, foreign investment and the financial sector, bypassing agriculture. The next round of reforms that is needed for raising India’s potential growth rate beyond 7–8 per cent should essentially have agriculture as an important component.
The persistence of high inflation is rooted in the inability to raise food production in step with the rise in demand arising from increasing population and per capita income growth. The present ‘subsidy-control regime’ in agriculture is strangling the farmer and preventing him from achieving a breakthrough in production. The input subsidies provided through low or no price for water, electricity and urea fertilisers not only lead to overuse and erosion of soil fertility, but also ensures inefficient production of these inputs by companies. Farmers can sell their products only through government markets which involve a large number of intermediaries and lower prices. Consumer subsidies administered through the public distribution system lead to low food prices which scarcely reach the consumers as large scale leakages take place. On the other hand, the government’s food procurement with periodical hiking of the procurement prices leads to market shortages and rising food prices.
Agricultural reform is the key to controlling inflation. That should involve lifting of government controls on pricing of all inputs and outputs, abolition of the monopsony of government mandis and administering all subsidies through direct cash transfers to poor farmers (owning land below two hectares) and poor consumers (below the poverty line).
Mathew Joseph is a Senior Consultant at the Indian Council for Research and International Economic Relations (ICRIER), New Delhi.
- India: Controlling inflation without hurting growth
- Indian monetary policy and the RBI – Let’s focus upon inflation
- India’s need for a counter-inflation subsidy
Continue reading here:
India’s seasons of inflation?
Asean
Deadly Floods and Landslides Strike Indonesia and Thailand – Vietnam Plus
At least seven people were killed, two others were injured and some were likely to be missing after flash floods and landslides hit the Indonesian eastern province of Maluku on the morning of August 25, according to the locality’s disaster management and mitigation office.
Heavy rainfall, which began on August 24, has triggered the disasters in Ternate city. Many local residents are in urgent need of support, authorities said.
Soldiers, police, local search and rescue personnel, disaster management staff, and volunteers are all involved in the ongoing rescue efforts, which include evacuating those trapped by the landslides and recovering materials from homes swept away by the floods.
Meanwhile in Thailand, local authorities reported that the death toll from a landslide in the popular resort province of Phuket on August 23 has risen to 13, including a Russian couple.
Source : Floods, landslides kill many in Indonesia, Thailand – Vietnam Plus
Asean
Tug of War in Southeast Asia: Can ASEAN-China Dialogue Shift the Scales Toward Peace? – An Analysis
The ASEAN-China dialogue is vital for regional stability, addressing economic cooperation and security challenges, particularly in the South China Sea, amidst significant geopolitical complexities and ongoing territorial disputes.
ASEAN-China Dialogue: A Path Towards Cooperation
The ASEAN-China dialogue plays a pivotal role in Southeast Asia’s diplomacy, fostering economic collaboration while addressing security challenges. Despite advances, particularly in managing tensions in the South China Sea, significant barriers remain to achieving lasting peace and stability in the region. ASEAN’s capacity to maintain its unity and centrality is crucial amidst complex power dynamics involving China and other global players.
Navigating Tensions and Economic Relations
A pressing concern within this dialogue is the South China Sea territorial disputes, which involve multiple ASEAN states and China. The militarization of the area raises alarm among regional stakeholders, necessitating urgent negotiations for a Code of Conduct (COC) to manage conflicts. Additionally, the growing economic interdependence fostered by initiatives like the Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership (RCEP) strengthens ASEAN-China ties, yet it also raises concerns about potential political leverage influencing member states’ autonomy.
The Challenge of Regional Stability
While the ASEAN-China dialogue offers a framework for promoting peace, its effectiveness is conditioned by broader geopolitical contexts, including China’s rivalry with the United States. The success of this dialogue rests on sustaining a commitment to multilateralism and peaceful dispute resolution. As ASEAN adapts to these complex dynamics, it must reinforce its unity and cooperative strategies, ensuring the region’s stability amid evolving challenges.
Source : Tug Of War In Southeast Asia: Will ASEAN-China Dialogue Tip The Balance Towards Peace? – Analysis
Asean
Cambodia Invites Business Leaders to Join the 21st China-ASEAN Expo in Nanning
Cambodia invites businesspeople to the 21st China-ASEAN Expo in Nanning, promoting trade and investment with incentives like hotel coupons and networking opportunities in various sectors.
Cambodia Invites Participation in CAEXPO 2024
Cambodia is actively encouraging business leaders, investors, and service providers to participate in the upcoming 21st China-ASEAN Expo (CAEXPO), set to take place from September 24-28 in Nanning, China. According to a Ministry of Commerce announcement, CAEXPO serves as a vital platform for trade and investment collaborations between ASEAN nations and China.
To facilitate Cambodian participation, the Ministry invites interested individuals to apply as Trade Visitors by August 31, 2024. Participants will benefit from hotel coupons, dining vouchers, and shuttle services to the expo venue. Furthermore, attendees can engage in business matchmaking in sectors such as food processing, digital technology, and renewable energy products.
Kin Phea, from the Royal Academy of Cambodia, emphasized the advancements in China-ASEAN relations, particularly concerning economic cooperation, tourism, and cultural exchanges. He noted that both sides have become each other’s largest trading partners, enhancing collaboration through the Belt and Road initiative, focusing on infrastructure and sustainable development.
Source : Cambodia encourages businesspeople to partake in 21st China-ASEAN Expo in Nanning